M Jashim Ali Chowdhury
Assistant Professor, Department
of Law, University of Chittagong
Published in the Daily Star, law and Our Rights, April 30, 2019
Parliament of Bangladesh has been subject to a lot of historical, institutional and doctrinal analysis over the years. Authors invariably ended up in suggesting varieties of reforms in the form of a to-do check list on an immediate, short-term and long-term basis. Actual reforms undertaken so far also remain piecemeal, short-sighted, popularity tilted, theoretically flawed and procedurally misguided. Proposition of this write up is that meaningful reform in future would require a sound doctrinal approach suitable to a Westminster style parliament. In this regard, the rational choice and historical institutional approaches might prove better than our traditional evolutionary and revolutionary understanding of parliamentary reform. By taking a historical institutional approach, we travel beyond changes by mere chance and accident. We rather investigate why, when and how reforms are proposed, rejected or made.
Evolutionary account of political reform focuses on culture influenced changes emerging gradually
over a long stretch of time. While evolutionary and historical accounts may
serve a descriptive narration of events in a chronological fashion, it does not
serve the explanatory and justificatory aspects of reform. Evolutionary
theories thereby fail to explain why institutions are created on the first
place, why those are maintained and why changes are resisted or even adopted
nominally or significantly by the individuals and groups.
Big Bang or Revolutionary approaches on the
other hand see institutions emerging suddenly, either by armed revolution or by
specially called constitutional conventions or assemblies or by mix of the two.
Speaking from a Westminster perspective, revolutionary approaches to reform
appear defective for two reasons. Firstly, the revolutionary body or leadership
reflects the “general will” of the people at the time of crisis who seeks to
stabilize the situation as quickly as possible. Unless bound by exceptional
amount of will force, the revolutionary regimes are more interested in
achieving the stability the quickest. Changes brought are mostly crispy,
populists, minimal and facial. Secondly, revolutionary attempts have not always
resulted in liberal democratic reforms. Emergence of even more repressive
regimes is not quite uncommon.
Given the
inadequacy of evolutionary and revolutionary approaches, Professor Roger D.
Congleton’s Constitutional Bargain Model
might offer an incentive driven intermediate form of reforms. Incentive driven
explanation of reform reflects a sort of rational choice institutionalism that attempts
a trade-off between proposed reform and the price that needs be paid for that.
Is the proposed reform profitable for both the reformers (who gain something)
and incumbent power holders (who lose something)? Congleton argues that reforms
will be bargained over and (occasionally) adopted only when the existing
beneficiaries see that their immediate interest remains guarded, though the
institution changes.
Historical
institutional approach would acknowledge the role of the political
context affecting the proposed reform and explain why and how institutional norms and values impact
on reform in the way they do. Institutions have structures and procedures side
by side with well-defined values, norms, interests, identities and beliefs. Like
the constitutional bargain model, the institutional accounts of reforms
recognise path dependence of reform initiatives. Acknowledging ‘path
dependency’ of reform would help us understand why some attempts fail and others
succeed. Reforms would be successful when the path is ready to be altered,
under a surmountable amount of political pressure for change.
Therefore, a reform
advocate would need to ask and answer three questions - Why reform? Why now?
And why some of the reform proposals fail while others succeed? In that sense,
reforms will be possible only when the following three conditions are
fulfilled: First, there must be a window of opportunity for the reform to occur
e.g., beginning of parliament or fortuitous circumstances brewing the climate
for reform. Second, there must be coherent reform agenda to provide a package
behind which the members of parliament may unite. Third, there must be
leadership (political will) behind to take the reform package through the
parliament (Alexandra Kelso, Parliamentary
Reform at Westminster, Manchester University Press, 2013).
Within a
Westminster parliamentary set up for example, parliamentary process is being
drained into executive dominance. Ministerial responsibility convention is
utilised to undermine the accountability and scrutiny of government instead.
Partisanship operates to whip and discipline individual MPs. In presence of
these institutional norms and values to the advantage of the government and
party elites, it appears difficult that there will be enough “political will”
to change the status quo. Question therefore is - how could we be hopeful of
change in terms of enhancement of parliamentary authority in Bangladesh?
A cursory look over the history of reform initiatives in Bangladesh would
reveal that in case of original revolutionary authority of 1972, conditions of
favourable climate, coherent package and concrete political will were satisfied
and hence the reform was swift and decisive. As indicated in Big Bang theories
above, the ‘revolutionary’ changes attempted by military regimes of 70s and 80s
ended in enhancing the executive’s authority instead. Climate of change might
have been there, but not the coherent agenda or political good will towards the
right direction. In case of the revolutionary impulse of early 1990s, climate
of change and coherent agenda were there but not the sincerest of political
wills to materialise the dream for a meaningful parliamentary system. Since
then there have been several donor-led studies into the parliamentary process of
Bangladesh. The most robust one was the Strengthening Parliamentary Democracy
Project (SPD) funded by UNDP, World Bank etc. Starting in 1997, the project
aimed at encouraging changes in the Rules of Procedure and capacity building for
the committees and individual members. The project unfortunately ended in such
a disarray that UNDP had to discontinue the funding in 2007. In this case we didn’t
see the climate, agenda or political will necessary for meaningful reform.
As for the present,
our long struggle with successive parliaments suggests that we already know
what type of reforms we need. With the installation of a new parliament
recently, the window of opportunity is also there. Only thing the advocacy and
citizens’ groups now need to do is inducing some willingness in the political
force in power. Now the only question boiled to be answered is - Who is to bell
the cat?